[PDF] 1 Lecture Notes - Production Functions - 1/5/2017 D.A. 2





Previous PDF Next PDF



Chapter 3: Functions Lecture notes Math Section 1.1: Definition of

Lecture notes. Math. Section 1.1: Definition of Functions. Definition of a function. A function f from a set A to a set B (f : A ? B) is a rule of 



Lecture Notes on Cryptographic Boolean Functions

Lecture Notes on Cryptographic Boolean Functions. Anne Canteaut. Inria Paris



MATH 221 FIRST SEMESTER CALCULUS

This is a self contained set of lecture notes for Math 221. The subject of this course is “functions of one real variable” so we begin by wondering what ...



1 Submodular functions

Lecture date: November 16 2010. 1 Submodular functions. We have already encountered submodular functions. Let's recall the definition.



MATH 551 LECTURE NOTES GREENS FUNCTIONS FOR BVPS

MATH 551 LECTURE NOTES. GREEN'S FUNCTIONS FOR BVPS. Topics covered. • Distributions (briefly). ? Heaviside function. ? Dirac delta. • Green's functions 



generating-function-notes.pdf

18.310 lecture notes. March 1 2015. Generating Functions. Lecturer: Michel Goemans. We are going to discuss enumeration problems



Extensions of functions - lecture notes Krzysztof J. Ciosmak

Theorem 1.3 (McShane). Suppose that A ? X and that f : A ? R is a. Lipschitz function. Then there exists an extension of f i.e. a function 



146 Chapter 13. The Trigonometric Functions (LECTURE NOTES 9)

Definitions of the Trigonometric Functions (LECTURE NOTES 9). 149. (10) x y t = /3. (x



1 Lecture Notes - Production Functions - 1/5/2017 D.A. 2

5 Jan 2017 1 Lecture Notes - Production Functions - 1/5/2017 D.A. ... For this lecture note we will work with a simple two input Cobb-Douglas ...



Notes 10 for CS 170 1 Bloom Filters

27 Feb 2003 Last lecture we saw one technique that deals with this phenomenon but still allows us to use simple hash functions: in universal hashing.



[PDF] Chapter 3: Functions Lecture notes Math Section 11 - CORE

Chapter 3: Functions Lecture notes Math Section 1 1: Definition of Functions Definition of a function A function f from a set A to a set B (f : A ? B) 



[PDF] Math 150 Lecture Notes Introduction to Functions

Math 150 Lecture Notes Introduction to Functions The term function is used to describe a dependence of one quantity on another A function f is a rule 





[PDF] Lecture 1 (Review of High School Math: Functions and Models)

Lecture 1 (Review of High School Math: Functions and Models) Introduction: Numbers and their properties (Note: division by 0 is always undefined!)





[PDF] Math 111 Lecture Notes - Section 11: Functions

Math 111 Lecture Notes Section 1 1: Functions A set containing ordered pairs (x y) defines y as a function of x if and only if no two ordered pairs



[PDF] Functional Analysis Lecture Notes - Michigan State University

These are lecture notes for Functional Analysis (Math 920) Spring 2008 The text for this course is Functional Analysis by Peter D Lax John Wiley Sons 



[PDF] MTS 102 LECTURE NOTE FUNCTIONS LIMITS AND

%2520LIMITS%2520AND%2520CONTINUOUS%2520FUNCTION%2520A.pdf



[PDF] Lecture Notes on Function Spaces

Which topics in the lecture? Comment Where in the Notes? Adams/Fournier Sobolev Spaces [1] Sobolev Spaces Orlicz Spaces Functions on Domains

:

1 Lecture Notes - Production Functions - 1/5/2017 D.A.

2 Introduction

Production functions are one of the most basic components of economics

They are important in themselves, e.g.

-What is the level of returns to scale? -How do input coe¢ cients on capital and labor change over time? -How much heterogeneity is there in measured productivity across ...rms, and what ex- plains it? -How does the allocation of ...rm inputs relate to productivity Also can be important as inputs into other interesting questions, e.g. dynamic models of industry evolution, evaluation of ...rm conduct (e.g. collusion) For this lecture note, we will work with a simple two input Cobb-Douglas production function Y i=e0K1iL2ie"i whereiindexes ...rms,Kiis units of capital,Liis units of labor, andYiis units of output. soil quality, management quality)

Take natural logs to get:

y i=0+1ki+2li+"i

This can be extended to

-Additional inputs, e.g. R&D (knowledge capital), dummies representing discrete tech- -Later we will see more ‡exible models y i=f(ki;li;) +"i y i=f(ki;li;"i;)(with scalar/monotonic"i) y i=0+1iki+2ili+"i

3 Endogeneity Issues

Problem is that inputski,liare typically choice variables of the ...rm. Typically, these choices are made to maximize pro...ts, and hence will often depend on unobservables"i. Of course, this dependence depends on what the ...rm knows about"iwhen they make these input choices. 1 Example: Suppose a ...rm operating in perfectly competitive output and input markets (with respective pricespi;ri, andwi) perfectly observes"ibefore optimally choosing inputs. Pro...t maximization problem is: max K i;Lipie0K1iL2ie"iriKiwiLi FOC"s will imply that optimal choices ofKiandLi(kiandli) will depend on"i. Intuition: use more inputs.

As a result, one cannot estimate

y i=0+1ki+2li+"i using OLS becausekiandliare correlated with"i. Generally one would expect coe¢ cients to be positively biased. Similar problems would arise in more complicated models (e.g. non-perfectly competitive output or input markets,"ionly partially observed), except the special case where the ...rm has no knowledge of"iwhen choosing inputs Ifkiis a "less variable" input thanli, one might expect the ...rm to have less knowledge about iwhen choosingki(relative toli). Generally, this will implykiwill be less correlated with ithanliis:So one might expect more bias in the labor coe¢ cient. Note: we will generally assume that the unobservables"iare generated or evolve exogenously, i.e. they are not choice variables of the ...rm. Things get considerably harder when the unobservables are choice variables of the ...rm. WLOG, lets think about"ihaving two components, i.e. y i=0+1ki+2li+!i+i where!iis an unobservable that is predictable (or partially predictable) to the ...rm when it makes its input decisions, andiis an unobservable that the ...rm has no information about when making input decisions (e.g.!irepresents average weather conditions on a particular farm,irepresents deviations from that average in a given year (after inputs are chosen)).i could also represent measurement error in output. In this formulation,!iis causing the endogeneity problem, noti. Let"s call!ithe "produc- tivity shock".

4 Traditional Solutions

Two traditional solutions to endogeneity problems can be used here: instrumental variables approaches. 2

4.1 Instrumental Variables

Want to ...nd "instruments" that are correlated with the endogenous inputs, but do not directly determineyiand are not correlated with!i(andi). Good news is that theory can provide us with such instruments. Speci...cally, consider input and output priceswi,ri, andpi:Theory tells us that these prices from the production function as they do not directly determine outputyiconditional on the inputs. Last requirement is thatwi,ri, andpiare not correlated with the productivity shock!i.

When will this be the case (or not be the case)?

One key issue is the form of competition in input and output markets. -If output markets are imperfectly competitive (i.e. ...rms face downward sloping demand curves), then a higher!iwill increase a ...rm"s output, drivingpidown. In other words, p iwill be positively correlated with!i, invalidatingpias an instrument. -If input markets are imperfectly competitive (i.e. ...rms face upward sloping supply curves), then a higher!iwill increase a ...rm"s input demand, drivingwiand/orriup. Sowiand/orriare now correlated with!i, invalidating them as instruments. So for these instruments want ...rms operating in perfectly competitive input or output mar- kets. Typically, this is more believable for input markets than for output markets. Unfortunately, even if willing to make these assumptions, IV solutions haven"t been that broadly used in practice. First, one needs data onwiandri. Second, there is often very little variation inwiandriacross ...rms (often there is a real question of whether ...rms actually things like variation in unobserved labor quality (i.e. the ...rm with the higherwiis employing workers of higher quality). If the latter, thenwiis not a valid instrument. While there might be "true" variation in input prices across time, this is usually not helpful, because if one has data across time, one often wants to allow the production function to change across time, e.g. y it=0t+1kit+2lit+!it+it (though there could be exceptions) That said, I think if one can ...nd a market where there is convincing exogenous input price variation, IV approach is probably more convincing than the approaches I will talk about in the rest of this lecture note, as there seem to be less auxiliary assumptions.

Notes:

-Randomized experiments - either directly manipulating inputs, or manipulating input prices. 3 -As is typically done in this literature, I have implicitly made a "homogeneous treatment y i=0+1iki+2ili+!i+i and Imbens (1994, Ecta) -If there are unobserved ...rm choice variables in!i, it becomes quite hard to ...nd valid instruments, even with the above assumptions. This approach relies on having panel data on ...rms across time, i.e. y it=0+1kit+2lit+!it+it Assume thatitis independent acrosst(this is consistent withitnot being predictable by the ...rm when choosingkitandlit) assumption), i.e. it=!i y ity i=1kitk i+2litl i+ (it i) y ityit1=1(kitkit1) +2(litlit1) + (itit1) that we have assumed that theit"s are uncorrelated with input choices) these equations can be estimated with OLS.

Problems:

-1)!it=!iis a strong assumption -2) These estimators often produce strange estimates. In particular, they often generate very small (or even negative) capital coe¢ cients. Perhaps this is due to measurement error in capital (Griliches and Hausman (1986, JoE))?

Other notes:

inputs to be uncorrelated with current and laggedit. Usingkit1andlit1(or other lags) as instruments for(kitkit1)and(litlit1), one can allow current inputs to be arbitrarily correlated with pastit"s (sequential exogeneity) 4 -Panel data approach can be extended to richer error structures (Arellano and Bond (1991, ReStud), Arellano and Bover (1995. JoE), Blundell and Bond (1998, JoE, 2000,

ER), Arellano and Honore (2001, Handbook)) e.g.

it=!it1+it or it=i+itwhereit=it1+it

I will talk further about these these later.

4.3 First Order Conditions

A third approach to estimating production functions is based on information in ...rst order conditions of optimizing ...rms. For example, for a ...rm operating in perfectly competitive input and output markets, static cost minimization implies that @Y@L LY =wLpY @Y@K KY =rKpY i.e. the output elasticity w.r.t. an input must equal its (cost) share in revenue. In a Cobb-Douglas context, these output elasticities are the production function coe¢ cients

1and2, so observations on these revenue shares across ...rms could provide estimates of

the coe¢ cients. Note thatrcan often be assumed known and often one directly observeswLandpY(rather thanLandY- i.e. labor input and output are measured in terms of dollar units (that are implicitly assumed to be comparable across ...rms)) But: -This assumes static cost minimization - i.e. it assumes away dynamics, adjustment costs, etc.. At the very least we often think about the capital input being subject to a dynamic accumulation process, e.g.Kit=Kit1+iit1 -There are additional terms when ...rms are not operating in perfectly competitive mar- kets, e.g. when ...rms face downward sloping demand curve @Y@L LY =wLpY @Y@K KY =rKpY where=pmc ;i.e. percentage markup. Note that pro...t maximization impliespmc =1+, whereis the elasticity of demand. So, for example, one could still identify production coe¢ cients using this method if the elasticity of demand was known (this is done in Hsieh and Klenow (2009, QJE)). Or, one might be able to identify both with additional restrictions, e.g. Constant Returns to Scale (related to Hall (1988, JPE)). 5

5 Olley and Pakes (1996, Ecta)

Alternative approach to estimating production functions. I will argue that key assumptions are timing/information set assumptions, a scalar unobservable assumption, and a monotonic- ity assumption.

Setup:

y it=0+1kit+2lit+!it+it(1) Again, the unobserved productivity shocks!itare potentially correlated withkitandlit.but the unobservablesitare measurement errors or unforecastable shocks that are not correlated with inputskitandlit. Basic Idea: Endogeneity problem is due to the fact that!itis unobserved by the econome- trician. If some other equation can tell us what!itis (i.e. making it "observable"), then the endogeneity problem would be eliminated. Olley and Pakes will use observed ...rms"investment decisionsiitto "tell us" about!it:

Assumptions:

1)The productivity shock!itfollows a ...rst order markov process, i.e.

p(!it+1jIit) =p(!it+1j!it) whereIitis ...rmi"s information set att(which includes current and past!it"s). Note: -This is both an assumption on the stochastic process governing!itandan assumption on ...rms"information sets at various points in time. Essentially, ...rms are moving through time, observing!itatt, and forming expectations about future!itusingp(!it+1j!it). -The form of this ...rst order markov process is completely general, e.g. it is more general than!it=!ior!it.following an AR(1) process. -This assumption implies that

E[!it+1jIit] =g(!it)

and that we can write it+1=g(!it) +it+1where by constructionEit+1jIit= 0 -g(!it)can be thought of as the "predictable" component of!it+1,it+1can be thought of as the "innovation" component, i.e. the part that the ...rm doesn"t observe untilt+1: -This can be extended to higher order Markov processes (see ABBP Handbook article and Ackerberg and Hahn (2015))

2) Labor is a perfectly variable input, i.e.litis chosen by the ...rm at timet(after observing

it). pro...ts at periodt, not future pro...ts. This rules out, e.g. labor adjustment costs like ...ring or hiring costs. 6

4) On the other hand,kitis accumulated according to a dynamic investment process. Specif-

ically K it=Kit1+iit1 whereiitis the investment level chosen by the ...rm in periodt(after observing!it). Im- portantly, note thatkitdepends onlast period"sinvestment, notcurrentinvestment. The assumption here is that it takes full time period for new capital to be ordered, delivered, and installed. This also implies thatkitwas actually decided by the ...rm at timet1. This is what I refer to as a "timing assumption".

In summary:

-labor is a variable (decided att), non-dynamic input -capital is a ...xed (decided att1), dynamic input -We could also think about including ...xed, non-dynamic inputs, or variable, dynamic inputs. (see ABBP) future capital levels, a pro...t maximizing ...rm will chooseiitto maximize the PDV of its future pro...ts. This is a dynamic programming problem, and will result in an dynamic investment demand function of the form: i it=ft(kit;!it)(2)

Note that:

-kitand!itare part of the state space, butlitdoes not enter the state space. Why? -ftis indexed byt. This implicitly allows investment decisions to depend on other state variables (e.g. input prices, demand conditions, industry structure) that are constant across ...rms. -ftwill likely be a complicated function because it is the solution to a dynamic pro- gramming problem. Fortunately, we can estimate the production function parameters without actually solving this DP problem (this is helpful not only computationally, but also allows us to estimate the production function without having to specify large parts of the ...rms optimization problem (semiparametric)). This is a nice example of how semiparametrics can help in terms of computation - literature based on Hotz and Miller (1993, ReStud) is similar in nature. One of the key ideas behind OP is that under some conditions, the investment demand equation (2) can be inverted to obtain it=f1t(kit;iit)(3) i.e. we can write the productivity shock!itas a function of variables that are observed by the econometrician (though the function is unknown)

What are these conditions/assumptions?

-1) (strict monotonicity)ftis strictly monotonic in!it:OP prove this formally under a set of assumptions that include the assumption thatp(!it+1j!it)is stochastically increasing in!it. This result is fairly intuitive. 7 -2) (scalar unobservable)!itis theonlyeconometric unobservable in the investment equation, i.e. Essentially no unobserved input prices that vary across ...rms (if there were observed input prices that varied across ...rms, they could be included as arguments offt). There is one exception to this - labor input price shocks across ...rms that arenot correlated across time. ...ciency at doing investment, heterogeneity in adjustment costs, other heterogeneity in the production function (e.g. random coe¢ cients))

No optimization or measurement error ini

2) is a fairly strong assumption, but it is crucial to being able to write!itas an (unknown)

function of observables. Suppose these conditions hold. Substitute (3) into (1) to get y it=0+1kit+2lit+f1t(kit;iit) +it(4) Since we don"t know the form of the functionf1t(and it is a complicated solution to a dynamic programming problem), let"s just treat it non-parametrically, e.g. a high order polynomial iniitandkit, e.g. y it=0+1kit+2lit+ 0t+

1tkit+

2tiit+

3tk2it+

4ti2it+

5tkitiit+it(5)

Main point is that under the OP assumptions, we have eliminated the unobservable causing the endogeneity problem In this literature,iitis sometimes called a control variable and sometimes called a proxy variable. Neither is perfect terminology. So we can think about estimating this equation with a simple OLS regression ofyitonkit, l it, and a polynomial inkitandiit: Problem:1kitis collinear with the linear term in the polynomial, so we can"t separately identify1from But, there is nolitin the polynomial, so2can in principle be identi...ed (though see discussion of Ackerberg, Caves, and Frazer (ACF, 2015, Ecta) below) In summary, the "...rst stage" of OP involves OLS estimation of y it=2lit+e 0t+e

1tkit+

2tiit+

3tk2it+

4ti2it+

5tkitiit+it(6)

wheree 0t=0+

0tande

1t=1+

1t. This produces an estimate of the labor coe¢ cient

b 2 and an estimate of the "composite" term0+1kit+!it b it=be 0t+be

1tkit+b

2tiit+b

3tk2it+b

4ti2it+b

5tkitiit=d0+1kit+!it

8 To estimate the coe¢ cient on capital,1, we need a "second stage".

Recall that we can write

it=g(!it1) +itwhereE[itjIit1] = 0

Sincekitwas decided att1,kit2Iit1. Hence

E[itjkit] = 0

and therefore

E[itkit] = 0

This moment condition can be used to estimate the capital coe¢ cient More speci...cally, consider the following procedure: -1) Guess a candidate1 -2) Compute b!it(1) =bit1kit for alliandt.b!it(1)are the "implied"!it"s given the guess of1. If our guess is the true1,b!it(1)will be the true!it"s (asymptotically). If our guess is not the true

1, theb!it(1)"swill not bethe true!it"s asymptotically. (Note: Actually,b!it(1)is

really!it+0, but the constant term ends up not mattering) -3) Given the impliedb!it(1)"s, we now want to compute the impliedinnovationsin!it i.e. impliedit"s. To do this, consider the equation it=g(!it1) +it Think about estimating this equation, i.e. non-parametrically regressing the implied b!it(1)"s (from step 2) on the impliedb!it1(1)"s (also from step 2). Again, we can think of representinggnon-parametrically using a polynomial inb!it1(1). Call the residuals from this regressionbit(1) These are the implied innovations in!it. Again, if our guess is the true1,bit(1)will be the trueit"s (asymptotically). If our guess is not the true1, then thebit(1)"swill not bethe trueit"s. -4) Lastly, evaluate the sample analogue of the moment conditionE[itkit] = 0;i.e. 1N 1T X iX tb it(1)kit= 0 SinceE[itkit] = 0, this sample analogue should be approximately zero if we have guessed the true1. For other1, this will generally not equal zero (identi...cation) -5) Use a computer to do a non-linear search for theb1that sets 1N 1T X iX tb it(b1)kit= 0 9 -This is a version of the second stage of OP. It is essentially a non-linear GMM estimator Notes -1) Recap of key assumptions: First order markov assumption on!it(again can be relaxed to higher order (but Markov)) - note, for example, that the sum of two markov processes is not generally Timing assumptions on when inputs are chosen and information set assumptions regarding when the ...rm observes!it(this can be strengthened or relaxed - see

Ackerberg (2016))

Strict monotonicity of investment demand in!it(can be relaxed to weak monotonic- ity - see below) Scalar unobservable in investment demand (tough to relax, though one can allow otherobservablesto enter investment demand, e.g. input prices) -2) Alternative formulation of the second stage (more like OP paper) y it=0+1kit+2lit+!it+it(7) y it1kit2lit=0+g(!it1) +it+it(8) y it1kitb2lit=0+g(bit101kit1) +it+it(9) y it1kitb2lit=g(bit11kit1) +it+it(10)

So given a guess of1, one can regress

y it1kitb2lit on a polynomial in(bit1

1kit1)to recover impliedit+it"s, i.e.dit+it(1), and then use the moment condition

E[(it+it)kit] = 0

and sample analogue 1N 1T X iX t dit+it(1) k it= 0 to estimate1. -3) There are other formulations as well. For example, Wooldridge (2009, EcLet) suggests estimating both ...rst stage and second stage simultaneously. This has two potential advantages: 1) e¢ ciency (though this is not always the case, see, e.g. Ackerberg, Chen, Hahn, and Liao (2014, ReStud) , and 2) it makes it easier to compute standard errors (with two-step procedure, it is typically easiest to bootstrap). On the other hand, a disadvantage is that it requires a non-linear search over a larger set of parameters (1 plus the parameters ofgandf1t), whereas the above two step formulations only require a non-linear search for1(or1andg) -4) Note that there are additional moments generated by the model. The assumptions of the model imply thatE[itjIit1] = 0. This means that the impliedit"s should not only be uncorrelated withkit, but everything else inIit1, e.g.kit1,kit2,lit1,k2it...... (though notlit). These additional moments can potentially add e¢ ciency, but also result in an overidenti...ed model, which can lead to small sample bias. The extent to which one utilizes these additional moments is typically a matter of taste. 10 -5) Intuitive description of identi...cation First stage: Compare output of ...rms with sameiitandkit(which imply the same unobservables determiningyit(it), and so it identi...es the labor coe¢ cient. (But again, see ACF section below) y itb2lit=0+1kit+g(!it1) +it+it =0+1kit+g(bit101kit1) +it+it This variation inkitis uncorrelated with the remaining unobservables determining y it(itandit), so it identi...es the capital coe¢ cient (However, note that the "com- parison of ...rms with same!it1" depends on the parameters themselves, so this is not completely transparent intuition) -6) OP also deal with a selection problem due to the fact that unproductive ...rms may exit the market. The problem is that even if

E[itjkit] = 0

in the entire population of ...rms, E[itjkit;still in sample att]may not equal0and be a function ofkit Speci...cally, if a ...rm"s exit decision attdepends on!it(and thusit), then this second expectation is likely>0and depends negatively onkit(since ...rms with higherkit"s may be more apt to stay in the market for a given!itorit). OP develop a selection correction to correct for this, which I dont think I will go through (see ABBP for discussion). On the other hand, if exit decisions attare made at timet1(a timing assumption like that already being made on capital), then there is no selection problem, since in this case the exit decision is just a function ofIit1.

6 Levinsohn and Petrin (2003, ReStud)

Levinsohn and Petrin worry about the assumption that investment is strictly monotonic in it. Intuitively, this assumption implies that any two ...rms with the samekitandiitmust have the same!it. But in many datasets, especially in developing countries,iitis often 0 (e.g. in LP"s Chilean dataset, approximately 50% of observations have 0 investment) It seems like a strong assumption that all these ...rms have the same!it(givenkit). It seems more likely that there is some threshold!it below which ...rms invest 0: One can extend OP to allow weak monotonicity for the observations whereiit= 0, but this requires discarding these observations from the analysis (Aside: in this case, there is no selection issue as long as one uses the second stage momentE[(it+it)kit] = 0rather thanE[itkit] = 0(see Gandhi, Navarro and Rivers (GNR, 2015)). This is because one cannot compute impliedit"s for observations for whichiit= 0(but one can compute implied (it+it)for these observations)) 11 Anyway, given these problems with 0 investment and an unwillingness to throw away data, more likely to be strictly monotonic in!it. They use an intermediate input, e.g. inputs like materials, fuel, or electricity. These types of inputs rarely take the value 0.

Production Function:

y it=0+1kit+2lit+3mit+!it+it(11) wheremitis an intermediate input.mitis assumed to be a variable, non-dynamic input, like labor. Consider a ...rm"s optimal choice ofmit. Like investment in OP,mitwill be chosen as a function of the state variableskitand!it, i.e. m it=ft(kit;!it)(12) Assuming strict monotonicity, this can be inverted and substituted into the production func- tion y it=0+1kit+2lit+3mit+f1t(kit;mit) +it(13)

The rest follows exactly as in OP

-Estimateb2in ...rst stage (1and3cannot be identi...ed because they are inf1t) -Estimateb1andb3in second stage (Need additional moment here to identify the second parameter. LP use.E[(it+it)mit1] = 0orE[itmit1] = 0, though see Bond and

Soderbom (2005) and GNR )

7 Ackerberg, Caves, and Frazer (2015)

7.1 Critique

This paper examines the ...rst stage of LP and OP

Our question: Under what conditions is the labor coe¢ cientb2identi...ed in the ...rst stage?quotesdbs_dbs14.pdfusesText_20
[PDF] functions of flour in baking

[PDF] functions of ingredients worksheet

[PDF] functions of management pdf notes

[PDF] functions of mobile computing

[PDF] functions of propaganda

[PDF] functions of proteins

[PDF] functions of the nervous system

[PDF] functions of the respiratory system

[PDF] functions of the skin

[PDF] functions of theatre in society

[PDF] functions pdf

[PDF] functions pdf notes

[PDF] functions problems and solutions pdf

[PDF] fundamental analytical chemistry calculations

[PDF] fundamental of business intelligence grossmann w rinderle ma pdf